click here

Saturday, March 27, 2010

What the new Health Law does not do

Responding to my Jakarta Post op-ed article, two colleagues of mine Arya Gaduh and Puspa Amri raised some important points. Arya mentioned this book, and he pointed out the health reform might ignore some of the lessons from the study. He also raised a more fundamental question: will universal coverage improve health outcomes? Not so much, according to the research.

Puspa reminded me that the new Law touches very little, if nothing, on curbing the ever-increasing health cost. I admit, I overlooked this issue. Some of the measures were dropped earlier in the bargaining process. Lobbyists may have some roles, as this article suggests.

Thanks, mates!




Tuesday, March 23, 2010

Understanding the US health care debate (3)

Part III. The politics and controversies

The first part of the saga has just ended. President Obama finally signed the new Health Law, after the Congress earlier approved the Bill. The Law will be a major landmark for the Obama administration to push their health care reform.

With a 53% popular vote in the presidential election and a Democrat majority in both chambers of the Congress, pushing the reform seemed to be an easy job for Obama. In reality, it hasn’t been so. Republicans has pledged to block the reform, at least make it a hard-to-win battle.

Separating signal from the noise, the Republicans points were: 1) rejecting the establishment of a government-run commercial insurance which they argued will crowd-out the private insurance market, 2) allowing interstate competition of insurance companies, 3) reforming malpractice law, which had threatened doctors and hospitals with big lawsuit compensations, 4) a less costly reform involving less or no tax increase, but far fewer people would be covered by insurance. Plus some traditional Republicans issues like limiting illegal immigrants from purchasing government-funded insurance and prohibiting Federal money to finance abortion.

Learning from Clinton’s 1993 failure, Obama distanced himself (and the White House) from the micromanagement. He let the Democrats in Congress got bogged down in the details and wrestled with the opponents.

In November 2009, the House announced their version of the Bill. The version was a 1,990-page long. Many believed this version would be difficult to win. The Economist described the earlier version of the Bill as ‘soaking the rich.’ It was estimated to cost the government around US$1.5 trillion for the next 10 years, more than $1 trillion limit set by Obama. Moreover, it was not budget-neutral. It would add $239 billion to the deficit, although it included a tax increase for business with more than $250,000 per year in payroll and individuals earned more than US$350,000 a year. Plus a steep ‘surcharge’ for the wealthy.

Before Christmas, Senate came up with their version (the one which will later become the Law, with some adjustments). The procedure in the Congress requires both chambers to agree on an identical version of the Bill. This means both House and Senate would need to work on a new, merged version before going back to the voting process. The Bill is said to cost US$940 billion for the next decade, and the impact on budget deficit is US$138 lower than the baseline scenario. It aims to provide cover for 32 million out of 47 million uninsured by 2019. Still not a universal coverage, but coverage rate will increase from 85% to 94%.

Until December, this still looked to be an easy process. With a 60-seat supermajority in the Senate, Republicans would not be able to block the Bill through filibuster – keep delaying the vote on and on by continue debating a bill. But in January, Scott Brown won the Massachusetts Senate seat vacated by the late Ted Kennedy. This made him the 41st Republican in the Senate, eliminating Democrat’s supermajority power.

Obama and his party had to switch strategy. Instead of working on a merged Bill, the House would vote for the Senate version. In this case, only 51 votes (simple majority) will be required in Senate. Later they would be able to tweak some of the clauses through what is called ‘budget reconciliation’ process. (This strategy enraged Republicans. But in truth, both parties had used this in the past.)

In February, the Obama revealed their version of the Bill, after a gathering called ‘bipartisan summit’. Practically, it was similar to the Senate Bill, except for some minor clauses regarding fines for individuals not having insurance. Later Obama also asked Harry Reid, Senate Democratic Leader and Nancy Pelosi, House speaker, to ‘consider’ some Republicans ideas: malpractice law reform and an oversee board for insurance fraud.

But the Democrats also needed to deal with internal challenges. Conservative Democrats rejected the idea that Federal money could be used to finance abortions. Democratic Hispanic Caucus concerned if illegal immigrants would be barred to purchase government insurance using their own money. On the other hand, left-wing Democrats questioned why the Bill does not contain establishing a public or government-run insurance company.

The internal lobby still took place until the last minute before the voting took place on Sunday, March 21. But in the end 219 voted ‘yes’, while 212 – all 178 Republicans and 34 Democrats – voted ‘no.’ (Many gave the biggest credit to Nancy Pelosi). The next step was mere formality. The Senate passed the bill, and in March 23 Obama signed the Bill into Law.

The Law is only the first test for the reform. The Obama administration will face other big tests. How fast the administration could start the reform (and how feasible it is in practice). Will the reform cost not blow out of what was estimated? And, more importantly, will it improve the health indicators? Not to mention another battle with the Republicans, and the states.

See also: The new Health Law, what will it do?

Readings on Indonesia's health sector

Two good reports by the World Bank: Investing in Indonesia's Health (2008) and Health Financing in Indonesia: a Reform Road Map (recent).

Monday, March 22, 2010

The new Health Law, what will it do?

Immediate benefits:

  • Insurance companies are prohibited to impose annual or lifetime caps.
  • US$5 billion funds are pledged to provide temporary coverage for uninsured individuals with pre-existing conditions.
  • Children can stay on their parents’ health insurance until they turn 26.
  • Drug discount for seniors.

By 2014:

  • All US residents is required to have health insurance, or face a fine of up to US$95 or 1% of their annual income in 2014, gradually increase to US$695 or 2.5% of their annual income.
  • A health insurance exchange will help small businesses negotiate with insurance companies.
  • Medicaid expansion and tax break for families.

By 2019:

  • Expand medical insurance coverage to 32 million.

Source: CNN. See more details here and here.


The new health care bill

The new bill looks to become law after the House voted to pass the Senate version. I am working on part III of my 'Understanding the US health care debate' series, which will include the current politics and result.

In the meantime, here's a good post by Greg Mankiw. Don't mean to spoil the party, but always good to have someone reminding not too get too drunk after a party. The bottom line is every choice has its trade-off. The challenge for policy people is how to minimize the trade-off.


Thursday, March 18, 2010

Understanding the US health care debate (2)

Part II. Earlier attempts to fix the system

Many initiatives and proposed solutions to the health care system have been revolving around increasing coverage and reducing costs (see my earlier post about the problems). Options for increasing coverage include mandating individuals to purchase health insurance (and imposing a fee for those who opt not to), usually combined with subsidies for the poor, and providing tax-incentives. Many analysts and politicians believe the US should have an individual mandate. Without it, many young, healthy individuals may choose to be uninsured, means the average health among the pool of insured will go down, hence insurance premium will stay high or go higher.


Attempts to reduce cost range from introducing more competition to the insurance and health care market, imposing a cap on price, limiting what medical procedures that the government would reimburse, to introducing more complex and bureaucratic regulations or regulatory bodies.

The New York Times has a nice interactive timeline of the comprehensive history of US health care reform. I

Clinton's 1993 proposal

Introduced by President Bill Clinton, efforts was led by First Lady Hillary Clinton, who chaired the National Task Force (hence the nickname Hillarycare dubbed by the opponents). The key components of the plan were:
  1. Mandating all eligible U.S. citizens to purchase health care, and employers of all businesses and all sizes, to provide insurance for their workers.
  2. Standardizing benefits - the plan listed minimum coverages and maximum annual out-of-pocket expenses for each plan.
  3. Establish a National Health Board in charge of regulating all health care in the country.

The proposal, as we know it, failed. Many possible explanations on why it failed. But the most common arguments are it was too complex, too ambitious, and
lack of incrementalism - although moving to single-payer system, oddly, was not part of the plan. Later in 2000, Mrs. Clinton remarked that the US needs a more step-by-step approach in achieving universal coverage.

Partisan politics have off course contributed, though many analysts said that supports from Democrats grassroots were not too solid anyway. Then there was also resistance from the big pharmaceutical companies. Plus, an economic dip in the early days of the administration did not help. But the Clintons were also criticized for their lack of efforts in reaching out to the opponents and making the plan simpler for the wider audience.

Massachusetts 2006 reform

In 2006, the Commonwealth of Massachusetts enacted a Law that requires nearly every resident to obtain health insurance. Through the Law, the Commonwealth government also provides free health care and partial subsidies for low-income residents. The Law was a result of a bipartisan coalition. However, the original proposal was initiated by then governor and 2008 Republican primaries candidate Mitt Romney.

Another aspect of the plan is the creation of a health insurance “exchange.” Basically, it was a clearing house to help small firms from conducting complex negotiations with insurers. Employees will be able to choose any plan approved by the state-backed exchange, and their premiums will be deducted from their pay checks.


From Fall 2006 to Fall 2007, the number of uninsured among low-income adults dropped from 24% to 13%, while among the higher income the number dropped from 5% to 3%. As of 2008, overall rate of uninsured has dropped further to 2.6%. The Massachusetts reform has been widely referred to as the model for the national-level reform by both Clinton and Obama during the 2008 Democratic primaries (although it did not provide enough leverage for Mitt Romney himself).


However, it was not immune from criticisms. It has strained the state budget, and a future budget crisis may be a consequence, failed to reduce medical spending, has subsequently drawn funding away from crucial health resources such as emergency room care, in practice the plan is not affordable for many families, and increased queues for already crowded medical services.


Some smaller attempts


A bipartisan Patient's Bill of Right, articulating a list of positive rights which doctors and hospitals ought to provide patients, thereby providing information, offering fair treatment, and granting them autonomy over medical decisions, was debated in Congress, but failed to pass as a Law. In 2003, President George W. Bush signed a Law that expanded Medicare to cover prescription drugs. Health care reform was one of the issues during Bush-Kerry 2004 debate. But in his second term, there was no major initiatives. Instead, the Bush administration was locked in a heated debate on reforming the country's social security.


The 2008 presidential campaign

John McCain's proposal was in fact closer to traditional Democrat's position than many Republicans. He supported importing drugs from Canada, which should make him an enemy of the pharmaceutical industry. He wanted Medicare to negotiate bulk discounts with the industry, which was always opposed by the Republicans.

The differences were, first, instead of mandating individual, he proposed to give tax credits as incentives for individuals to purchase health insurance.

Second, to curb the overuse of technology and needless medical procedures, he wanted to change the incentives by scrapping payments for individual procedures in favour of giving fixed payments to doctors and hospitals for actually solving particular health problems.

Third, he also wanted to impose caps on damages for malpractice and rule out awards for punitive damages - something that would put him into a war with the lawyers.

In many ways, candidates Clinton and Obama's proposals were quite similar. Both proposals offered Massachusetts-like mandate-and-subsidy schemes. Both plans would also force insurance companies to provide coverage for all (for example, by making it illegal to turn down new applicants with pre-existing medical problems). Particularly for Clinton, hers was a substantial simplification of the 1993 ambitious plan.

The differences between those two were, first, Clinton's plan would require all individuals to have health insurance, while Obama's would only require children, hence his was less ambitious in achieving the universal coverage.

Second, Clinton planned to oblige all firms in all types and all industries to provide covers for their employees. She would also introduce a tax-break reform for employer-based coverage but small firms would be subsidized. Under Obama's plan, firms would also be required to provide insurance for their workers, but small firms would be exempted, and tax-break reform was not part of his proposal.

Bear in mind that these were their proposals as candidates. There is a big gap between the campaign and the White House version, as shown in history. They'd need to face battle with the Capitol Hill, as well as do reality checks. President Obama's health care plan has not been revealed until after a year. When it was finally revealed, it was not a clear one, while at least two versions of the bill, one by the House, the other - a stronger one - by the Senate, have been introduced. And the battle continues.


Tuesday, March 16, 2010

Understanding the US health care debate (1)

I am not an expert on the US health system, and at best I am remotely trying to follow the latest health care reform issues. So what I would write here will reflect my very basic and overly simplified understanding of the issue. There are some reasons why the current debate on the US health care reform is interesting as well as important to monitor.

First, it will be the biggest domestic policy test for the Obama’s administration. How it goes, and how it ends, will affect the support and legitimacy of the administration, and perhaps determine the fate of it. Second, depends on what version of the bill comes out in the end, it could be one of the biggest changes in a country’s health and insurance system in history. Third, it is a high-profile case on how ideology, pragmatism and day-to-day politics simultaneously affect the outcome of a policy. Some people would like to see this as a fight between the market and government-oriented, Democrat and Republicans. But the truth, it is much more complex than that. Fourth, Indonesians can learn from this process, from the debate, outcome and implementation, including the trade-offs of making one policy choice over another.

There are three major areas of the debate: the problem with the current US health care system, the proposed solutions, and the politics. The order of those three also somewhat reflects the degree of my understanding, from the most to the least.

Part I. The problem

The US health system faces two main problems: 1) a very high percentage of people are not covered by health insurance (with a high proportion of those with insurance are underinsured), 2) high and rising insurance and medical cost. These two are highly related to each other so it is difficult to disentangle what causes what. They also face other challenges: how to solve those two problems with minimal cost (means how not to increase the budget deficit and/or introducing more taxes), and without hampering health and medical innovations.

Coverage

The Economist frequently cited that in 2009 some 47 million US residents (around 15% of the population) are uninsured. This is slightly higher than 46.3 million in 2008 and 45.7 million in 2007. In 2007, 37 million of the insurance are working-age adults, with 27 million working at least part time.

High price is the main reason why they are uninsured. Individuals from low-income households are more likely to be uninsured. But high cost also drives individuals who could afford to buy opt to not purchasing one. The problem is they are the more healthy ones. This lowers the average health among the pool of insured individuals, raising the premium, hence drives the overall cost up.

But many private insurance companies also turn down ‘risky’ applicants; for example, those with pre-existing health problems, risky lifestyle or environment. Some people point this as discrimination, because individuals with risky environment tend to come from minority race, especially Latinos. In fact, more than 30% Latinos are uninsured, compared to 10% of white, non-Latinos.

Of the 85% individuals who have some kind of health insurance, 60% receive it through their employers (or employers of their spouses, partners or other family members). That means many individuals will lose their insurance if they or their family bread-makers lose their jobs. Some 9% purchase health insurance individually.

The government also provide health insurance through several schemes (Medicare, Medicaid, SCHIP, TRICARE, IHS and some state-provided ones). Public health insurance schemes provide coverage to some 28% Americans – there are some overlaps between the public and private coverage.

Cost

By far, the US health care system is the most expensive in the world. In 2007, total health expenditure accounts for 16% of GDP; other developed countries spend no more than 11% of their GDP. In the same year, the US spends $7,400 per person on health care. Around half of the spending goes to hospital care (31%) and physician/clinical service (21%). Ironically, with that level of spending, the US is one of the worst among developed countries in terms of health indicators.

What drives the health care cost? According to Kaiseredu.org, rising costs of medical technology and prescription drugs and high administrative costs (e.g. marketing, billing, which accounts for 7% of total cost) contribute from the supply side. On the one hand, technological progress has made the US health system is perhaps the most innovative and advanced in the world. But it means the consumer needs to bear some of the investment cost. On the other hand, this has also made the industry become more and more supply-driven; they generate demand for more intense and costly services, though not necessarily more effective. Similar story happens with the pharmaceutical industry.

From the demand or consumer’s side, demographic changes that have occurred over the past century have resulted in higher life expectancy, older population but also new, more complex health problems. Prevalence of chronic lifestyle-related illnesses has increased substantially.

Another contributing factor, although the relative contribution is still debatable, the legal process-related costs. According to one estimate, Medical malpractice lawsuit accounts for 5-10% of total medical cost each year. Medical service providers, facing high financial and reputation costs, are then ‘forced’ to perform extra procedures for patients.

There are also arguments pointing out that rising health care costs have been driven by the public insurance scheme (Medicare, Medicaid etc.). They are lack of competition, and the reimbursement system has created perverse incentives for medical care providers (see this or this). The other side of the argument blame more on private insurance companies because they have been overcharging consumers, so a cap on insurance premium needs to be introduced.


Tuesday, March 9, 2010

Missing women, again

It is often said that women make up a majority of the world's population. They do not. This mistaken belief is based on generalizing from the contemporary situation in Europe and North America, where the ratio of women to men is typically around 1.05 or 1.06, or higher. In South Asia, West Asia, and China, the ratio of women to men can be as low as 0.94, or even lower, and it varies widely elsewhere in Asia, in Africa, and in Latin America. How can we understand and explain these differences, and react to them?

editorial article from The New York Review of Books, December 20, 1990.

This week's The Economist published a special report on the growing worldwide gender imbalance at birth, especially in some developing countries. For example, the article cited:
In China the sex ratio for the generation born between 1985 and 1989 was 108, already just outside the natural range. For the generation born in 2000-04, it was 124 (ie, 124 boys were born in those years for every 100 girls). According to CASS the ratio today is 123 boys per 100 girls.

As the consequence, within ten years one in five young men would be unable to find a bride because of the dearth of young women—a figure unprecedented in a country at peace.

What caused the highly skewed ratio? According to the article, it is the combination of 1) parents' strong preference over boys (for whatever reasons - economic or cultural), 2) declining fertility, either by policy or improved income, so nowadays parents tend to have a limited number of children, and 3) advanced in technology; cheaper ultrasound makes it possible to detect gender of fetus, hence parents might decide to abort the unborn if it was a girl ('Gendercide', as the article refers to it).

The article also linked this trend to socio-cultural changes, including problems. In a highly homogeneous Korea, inter-country marriage becomes more common and acceptable. In some parts of India, a bride can only marry a man from a different village if the groom's village provides another bride in exchange. In China, growing number of unmarried men has created pressure to crime and violence.

* * *

Skewed male-female ratio in developing countries has been an interest for long. The cited paragraph in the beginning was a summary of a series of papers Sen has written in the 1980s.

Where did the number come from? Let's take 1.05 as the 'normal' ratio of women to men.1 It means that if a country like China has a ratio of 0.94, this alone amounted to more than 50 million deficit of women. Together with the female deficit in South Asia, Africa, and other developing countries, they added up to more than 100 million.2

The reason, as Sen argued, was 'discrimination' against girls in getting access to health care, medicine and nutrition. The term 'discrimination' here should be treated carefully. It may not be a clear case of discrimination, but different intra-household preference in allocating resources towards boys and girls, resulting in higher mortality rate of women compared to men.3

Some researchers have tried to come up with different explanations for the missing women. Emily Oster (2005) argued, Hepatitis-B could be one explanations. Unborn boys have more chance to survive if their mothers have Hep-B. High prevalence of Hep-B among pregnant mothers in those countries skews the gender ratio at birth towards boys. The missing girls were not missing, concluded Oster; they were never born at all. However, her later study in China with Gang Chen (2008) didn't show that Hep-B explains male-biased sex ratio. So the Hep-B hypothesis may still be doubtful.

That makes selective abortion, as reported in The Economist article, the likeliest. possible explanation, for now. Amartya Sen seems to agree. As he wrote in his 2003 article, revisiting his earlier one:
But another more important and radical change has occurred over the past decade.T here have been two opposite movements: female disadvantage in mortality has typically been reduced substantially, but this has been counterbalanced by a new female disadvantage—that in natality—through sex specific abortions aimed against the female fetus. The availability of modern techniques to determine the sex of the fetus has made such sex selective abortion possible and easy, and it is being widely used in many societies.

1 Sen defined gender ratio as the number of women divided by men. Many (most?) other calculation define it as the other way round, multiplied by a hundred. So a ratio 0f 106 means for every 100 women there are 106 men. Doesn't matter which one we prefers as long as we know what it is.
2 Using slightly different method, Klassen and Wink (2003) estimated a lower - but still large - number of 'missing' women, 89 million.
3See a paper by Monica DasGupta (1997) on how boys and girls received different allocations of health and nutrition, based on a survey data from India.

Friday, March 5, 2010

Investing in nutrition in developing countries

Why? Well, the answers are quite clear. As a form of human capital, nutrition affects individual productivity both directly (through greater ability to work) and indirectly (through cognitive and educational achievements).

The question for empirical researchers is: how do we know? Higher wages and income clearly increase demand for nutrition, and so do higher education (endogeneity bias). And it is also possible that a third variable simultaneously affect nutrition and income (omitted variable bias). Schultz (2003) pointed out these issues.

But many studies have tried to overcome those problems, using experimental, quasi-experimental or instrumental variables. Behrman (1993), also Thomas and Frankenberg (2002) documented those studies. One of the most widely cited experimental study is The Work and Iron Status Evaluation by Thomas et al. (2006).

Thursday, March 4, 2010

Geography, sanitation and diarrhea

I've been involved as a research assistant for a study on sanitation project in rural East Java. One of the tasks was supervising the data collection from more than 2,000 households in 160 villages in 8 districts (kabupaten) in East Java, between August and December 2008.

The most important information we'd want to collect is whether the household has access to 'improved sanitation.' Improved sanitation is based on an international definition. Basically, if the sanitation facility is just an open pit, open area or riverside, then it is 'unimproved.'

When I did the calculation of the percentage of households* with improved sanitation by district, I found a quite obvious geographical pattern. People in the Western part of East Java has higher rate of improved sanitation compared with those in the Eastern part. This could be due to different climate and soil type. But what is interesting for me is the geographical boundary also coincides with cultural boundary. The Western East Java are of 'Mataraman' sub-culture - with closer proximity to the Central Javanese. The Eastern side are predominantly Madurese, they don't even speak Javanese in that part.

Could culture explain the variation in sanitation behavior? Too early to conclude, since so many variables may interact with each other. But this could be a starting point to look further.

What is clear is there is a correlation between improved sanitation and diarrhea incidence among children under five. This suggests that an intervention aims to improve sanitation quality could be an effective measure to reduce diarrhea prevalence for children, among other illness.

The question is: how. The project in which I involved specifically deals with creating demand for improved sanitation through community-based promotion. It is not a subsidy or supply-side intervention. Is it effective? Ask me again by the end of the year when we are (supposedly) done with the study.

*Due to copy right issue I can not share the numbers here. Sorry.