Thursday, March 4, 2010
Will higher income improve nutrition?
Wednesday, March 3, 2010
Market failure and health care needs
Constructing risk preference
You have an equal chance of receiving either Rp1.6 million per month or Rp400 thousand per month, depending on how lucky you are. Option 1 guarantees you an income of Rp800 thousand per month. Which option will you choose?
You have an equal chance of receiving either Rp1.6 million per month or Rp200 thousand per month, depending on how lucky you are. Option 1 guarantees you an income of Rp800 thousand per month. Which option will you choose?
Tuesday, March 2, 2010
Not-so-encouraging results
Suppose you are offered two ways to earn some money. With option 1, you are guaranteed Rp800 thousand per month. With option 2, you have an equal chance of either the same income, Rp800 thousand per month, or, if you are lucky, Rp1.6 million per month, which is more. Which option will you choose?
After completing a series of further questions, the 'rational' individuals are categorized into for groups, from the most risk-averse to the most risk-loving. Half of them belong to the most risk-averse group; about a quarter are most risk-loving, 14 percent are somewhat risk-loving, and less than 10 percent are somewhat risk-averse (see picture). The distribution implies that the variations across group are quite small, which lead to a question whether we can see an interesting story from that.
- Since these are not true experiments but hypothetical, the noise may be big to infer anything.
- These are hypothetical risk question about money/income. But people may have a different answer if it involves health. So applying this type of gamble to health behavior may not be correct.
Monday, March 1, 2010
Choices of State Intervention
It matters not only whether government intervene, but also how they do it: the second essential question is what the public sector should do, given that some problem in the private market appears to warrant some public action.
- Inform, which may mean to persuade, but does not require anyone to do anything.
- Regulate, which determines how a private activity may be undertaken.
- Mandate, which obligates someone to do something and (usually, but not always) to pay for it.
- Finance health care with public funds.
- Provide or deliver services, using publicly-owned facilities and civil service staffs.
Saturday, February 27, 2010
Health capital and demand for health
*Grossman, Michael, "On the Concept of Health Capital and the Demand for Health," The Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 80, No. 2 (Mar. - Apr., 1972), pp. 223-255.The aim of this study is to construct a model of the demand for the commodity "good health." The central proposition of the model is that health can be viewed as a durable capital stock that produces an output of healthy time. It is assumed that individuals inherit an initial stock of health that depreciates with age and can be increased by investment. In this framework, the "shadow price" of health depends on many other variables besides the price of medical care. It is shown that the shadow price rises with age if the rate of depreciation on the stock of health rises over the life cycle and falls with education if more educated people are more efficient producers of health. Of particular importance is the conclusion that, under certain conditions, an increase in the shadow price may simultaneously reduce the quantity of health demanded and increase the quantity of medical care demanded.
Thursday, February 18, 2010
Clear diagnosis, uncertain remedy
Friday, February 5, 2010
Possible topic#2 - Risk Preference, Time Preference and Health-related Decisions
- Developing countries have lower quality of health: lower life expectancy, higher infant (and adult) mortality rate, etc. Is it because of supply constraint (availability of public services)? Household budget constraint? Or because people value ‘good health’ less?
- Budget constraints causes households or individuals highly prefers today’s income than long-term human capital investment (high discount rate). This could lead to fewer amount of HH budget allocated for own and/or children’s health
- Lower valuation of future health means individuals would engage in riskier health behavior, such as smoking, less exercise, bad dietary habit, not having health insurance
- Policy relevance: a) if risk and time preference do explain less investment on health and riskier behavior, then policies that promote changes in behavior/valuation will be relevant, b) otherwise, improving income/well-being will be the more relevant approach.
Tuesday, February 2, 2010
Why medical care market is different?
- The nature of demand. Demand for medical services is irregular and unpredictable. Medical services, apart from preventive services, afford satisfaction only in the event of illness, a departure from the normal state of affairs.
- Expected behavior of the Physician. A physician's behavior is supposed to be governed by a concern for the customer's (patient's) welfare, and regulated by a certain ethical codes, more than other profession.
- Product uncertainty. One consumes a medical service in expectation of recovery from illness. However, when we consume a medical service, we can not predict whether it will result in a recovery (and if it does, how long will it take).
- Supply conditions. Entry to the medical profession is restricted by licensing. It means supply is limited, hence increasing cost.
- Pricing. The nature of medical service enables seller to effectively (and extensively) discriminate price by, among other things, consumer's income.
*Kenneth J. Arrow, "Uncertainty and the Welfare Economics of Medical Care," The American Economic Review 53(5):940-73.
Monday, February 1, 2010
What is health economics?
Health economics is concerned with the optimum use of scarce economic resources for the care of the sick and the promotion of health, taking into account competing uses of these resources. The basic problems are of two kinds: the organization of the medical market, and the net yield of investment in people for health.
Consumer preferences are not an adequate guide to the optimum allocation of resourcesfor health. There are a number of reasons why this is so. For one thing, a consumer would prefer to avoid the illnesses which require use of resources for health purposes. For another, his neighbors benefit from the medical services he purchases, for example,"flu shots" during the recent influenza epidemic. Individual decisions undervalue health services, and would result in under production of these services unless supplemented by actions of private voluntary agencies and government.